Background Image
Previous Page  42 / 56 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 42 / 56 Next Page
Page Background

42

• Minimum cost scenario

- A simplistic

way is to assume that since these

systems are severely out-dated, it is

likely that they are near the end of

their life-cycle anyway. Upgrading to

the current code minimum cannot be

considered as an additional cost – hence

the abatement cost over a period of 5

years is simply : [zero investment cost –

(energy savings over 5 years)] /[energy

savings over 5 years]= -$5/kWh.

• Maximum cost scenario

- On the

other hand, for the unfortunate

(thankfully fictional) few who have

relatively recently installed new systems

but are still 35% less efficient than the

code minimum benchmark, they might

be required to install a completely new

set of building services that meet the

minimum requirement, and the cost will

thus be the entire set of systems!

• Typical scenario

- These two extreme

cases are used to illustrate the upper

and lower bounds of the costs, and the

real cost curve must lie somewhere in

between the two. The typical retrofit

scenario is used to illustrate a situation

where the systems are not new nor near

the end of its service life, and we only

need to partially upgrade the system to

achieve the required energy benchmark,

it is based on current project data (albeit

from 2014 not 2030).

• More than half of the retrofitting

initiatives have payback periods

of less than 5 years  – a 20%

rate of return (ignoring the

effects of inflation). This is

a favourable financial proposition,

for comparison, an unsecured loan

to a typical property developer/

management company yields an

interest rate of about 5%. Given

the overall size of the market, it

is potentially feasible for financial

institutions to develop structured

products to fund the retrofitting.

• An equally important point to

note is that, without other forces

to shift the market, it is necessary

to resort to measures that may

not be financially feasible to

achieve the 35% reduction. Hence

in the future, additional market

measures may be necessary  - tax,

rebates, trading to make these

proposition financiallyattractive.

This is obviously a fictional scenario

(unfortunately, we do not have access to

energy/cost data in 2030), but it points the

way towards how we might begin to analyse

the retrofit market in the future.

There are many different ways to look at the cost of these retrofits.